
|
African Population Studies
Union for African Population Studies
ISSN: 0850-5780
Vol. 12, Num. 1, 1997
|
African Population Studies/Etude de la Population Africaine, Vol. 12, No. 1, March/mars 1997
Urbanization
and the informal sector in the former South African ethnic homelands: a study
of parallel trading in Transkei
Nsolo
J. MIJERE
Department of Sociology,
University of Transkei, Umtata, South Africa
Code Number: ep97007
Abstract
This
article is a critical assessment of an aspect of the apartheid political economy
in the former homelands. Two arguments are advanced. First, the poverty of the
informal sector was a result of lack of capital investments in towns in Transkei
during the apartheid era. Furthermore, the smallness of the informal sector
and the dominance of the female population in the sector is a consequence of
migration of productive male labour force into the developed enclaves of South
Africa. Secondly, it is argued that the nature of urbanization mirrors the economic
development of the towns. With the transition to democracy, the socio-economic
underdevelopment may be reversed or at least transformed.
Le
présent article est une évaluation critique d'un aspect de l'économie
politique de l'Apartheid dans les anciens les homelands. Deux arguments sont
avancés. Dabord, la pauvreté du secteur informel est dû
à l'absence de dépenses d'investissement dans les villes du Transkei
à l'ère de l'Apartheid. En outre, le caractère réduit
du secteur informel et la prédominance de la population féminine
dans le secteur est une conséquence de la migration de la main-d'oeuvre
productive vers les enclaves développées d'Afrique du Sud. Ensuite,
lauteur soutient que la nature de l'urbanisation reflète le développement
économique de la ville. Avec la transition vers la démocratie,
le sous-développement socio-économique peut être jugulé
ou du moins transformé.
Introduction
The
rapid increase in the heterogeneous population of urban centres in Africa is
largely a colonial, apartheid and post-colonial phenomenon. Whenever peoples
of various racial and ethnic groups to settled and engaged in income-generating
commercial activities in one place they created, in such settlements, a new
way of life known as urbanization. Wirth (1938) defined urban settlements or
cities as relatively large, dense and permanent settlements of socially heterogeneous
peoples. One of the fundamental reasons for the rapid growth of the urban population
is the selective capitalist investments concentrated in such large or small
settlements. The consequences of these selective investments are: first, the
availability of income-generating opportunities, better infrastructures and
supra-structures, formal and informal marketing opportunities and glittering
and better life are associated with the modern cities. The administrative, economic
and political functions performed in modern towns constitute a second set of
pull factors. Urban centres, therefore, have become international and national
bureaucratic, political, economic, and socio-cultural power-bases. Consequently,
the modern urban settlements have become major destinations for national and
international employment seekers. In addition, with the rapid increase and density
of the heterogeneous population, the peoples by themselves have transformed
the urban settlements into large market places of infinite human wants. The
urbanites attempt to meet the infinite demands of the peoples through formal
and informal activities.
The
purpose of this paper is to examine the nature and relationship of urbanization
and informal parallel trading in the Transkei, former Xhosa homeland of South
Africa. This relationship is measured firstly in the context of the flow and
destinations of rural-urban migration in South Africa. Secondly, we shall examine
the limited wage employment options in the urban centres as catalysts of the
expansion of parallel or pavement trading in the towns in Transkei. Lastly,
we shall investigate the socio-economic and political forces that parallel traders
contend with in towns in Transkei.
Data
and method
The
data for this paper are from a survey research project conducted in ten district
towns of the former Transkei homeland. The project was undertaken in 1991-1992
and was funded by the University of Transkei. In this research we interviewed
a sample of 517 people. As no frame of informal traders was available in the
ten towns, we used a purposive method in selecting the sample. We chose people
who were selling fruits and vegetables, ornaments and cosmetics, clothes, food
and head gears and traditional medicinal herbs on the streets, pavements or
in the open air. In this study, we refer to these as informal traders, "parallel
traders" or micro-traders.
The
theory of parallel trading
Several
studies have defined informal sector (ILO-JASPA 1988, Mijere 1989, Seshamani
1990, Ncube 1991, and Yankson 1991) in terms of its dependence on the formal,
private and public sectors. The formal sectors such as the public or private
sectors of agriculture, textile and manufacturing industries and mining provided
goods and services utilized and sold in the informal sector. The urban settlements,
on the other hand, provided customers and infrastructures for the informal sector.
Thus parallel traders bought their merchandise from wholesalers and even retailers
in the urban shops. The wage employees in the formal private and public sectors
were the customers of the parallel trade. To a large extent, the expansion and
development of parallel retailing depended first on the unemployment rate. The
second factor for the growth of the informal sector was the strength of the
urban economy, characterized by money circulation from the formal sector and
the heterogeneity of the urban settlement itself. Lastly, and perhaps most importantly,
is the capital investments in the modern cities.
Yankson
(1991:4), in his study of Ghana, asked whether the "informal sector has autonomous
prospects for growth and long- term development." "Does it have an autonomous
dynamism for development or does it depend on the pattern of growth of the formal
sector/public and private?" He concluded correctly that the two sectors are
dependent on each other. Indeed the informal and formal sectors are two faces
of the capitalist phenomenon.
Other
social scientists have explored further the linkages between the informal and
formal sectors. Seshamani (1990) defined the informal sector as comprising "all
those activities which generate incomes that go unrecorded in the formal accounts
of the national economy". The linkage here is based on the incorporation or
non-incorporation of the informal trade incomes by the national or international
governments. Because the informal trade was not easy to regulate, it was perceived
as making no contributions to the State revenue. Our study will show the dependency
of the two sectors upon each other, and upon the urbanization phenomenon in
the Transkei.
In
their recent studies, Ncube (1991) and Yankson (1991) have, however, rejected
the "formal" and "informal" concepts in contemporary capitalist political economy.
They have preferred "pseudo formal", "non-formal", "unstructured" and "low-income".
Mary Osirim (1994) used the term micro-enterprise for the informal sector. The
disputes over these concepts may be attributed to the nature of the capitalist
phenomenon that incorporates all other modes of production and yet fails to
create gainful employment for the labour force. In the Transkei towns, the dispute
over the concepts were based on the absence or inadequacy of formal marketing
infrastructures. In reality, the so-called informal sector provided both formal
and informal marketing functions. Besides, as we will show below, the government
and municipal leaders have been looking for ways to regulate activities of the
informal sector.
Disputes
over the adjectives "formal" or "informal" reveal the modern employment and
unemployment realities faced by capitalist development in the modern world and
especially in the third world countries. Indeed, today, many government leaders
and business men and women in Africa have accepted and recognized the informal
sector business activities. They have reversed their hostilities to parallel
traders and abrogated the laws that restrained informal sector activities because
of the endemic structures of urban unemployment in the modern capitalist world.
In
this paper, therefore, we have preferred the term parallel trading to street,
pavement, sidewalk, open-air selling and informal trading, because this concept
embraces all aspects of this business. The term does not designate the places
where the business activities take place nor the manner of business. The term
"parallel trading" further incorporates the activities of "vendors" and "hawkers".
Furthermore, parallel businesses compare and compete with the so-called formal
businesses. Paradoxically, these two sectors are daughters/sons of the capitalist
system. They both facilitate capital accumulation.
The
structure of parallel trading
The
informal sector, comprising small productive and service activities, has become
a viable field of study and socio-economic activities. Many scholars have undertaken
research in the sub-fields of this sector. African researchers, such as Ncube
(1991), Seshamani (1991), Yankson (1991), Mijere (1989) have observed that this
sector is a post-colonial entrepreneurial phenomenon. In this era, the parallel
sector, whether productive or service, has emerged as viable economic business
due to the inability of the formal sector, both private and public, to create
job opportunities for the urban as well as the rural labour force, in the third
world countries of Africa, Asia and Latin America.
Ncube
(1991) observed that the informal sector consisted of the following three small
structures which were considered illegal in the colonial and apartheid periods:
- Production
and services. These included petty carpentry, building contractors, tailoring,
tin-smithing, basket-making, pottery, wood carving, car, radio and TV repairs,
stone crushing, mining etc. They were characterized by small-scale production,
labour-intensive and individual or household ownership.
- Credit/financial
activities and currency exchanges. This informal financial marketing
activities have come about because of the collapse of local African currencies
and the
over-evaluation of foreign currencies in the face of economic crisis
and the availability of foreign exchange. Currency markets (commonly known
as black
currency markets) have mushroomed on the streets in urban areas and immigration
posts to provide hard currencies to individual and small-scale business traders.
- Trading
and selling. These activities included buying and selling new and second
hand commodities such as agricultural produce, textile and manufacturing
goods,
cross-border trade in goods and services.
All
these petty, individual or family-owned business activities were labelled illegal
in the colonial and early post-colonial periods. As such, they were suppressed
by white colonial, apartheid and post-colonial authorities in order to protect
and promote the emerging formal businesses. In independent Zambia, Mijere (1989)
showed how the government and municipal law- enforcing agents harassed school
dropouts for selling single cigarette sticks to smokers. In persecuting the
"Mishanga Boys," as they were called, the police were enforcing Chapter 707
of the laws of Zambia, stating that no person should sell goods by way of business,
unless he or she was the holder of a licence. The law declared further that
a person contravening the provisions of the Act shall be guilty of an offence.
For the Mishanga Boys, however, their parallel trading was a self-created source
of income in a country that provided gainful employment to only 10 percent of
the labour force.
Similarly,
Tomaselli (1984) outlined the conflicts between the Transkei law- enforcing
agents and the hawkers. She argued firstly that street selling was a "refuge
occupation-- an occupation of last resort for unsuccessful work-seekers". Secondly,
she stated that the Transkei Government harassed and prosecuted street traders
for the following reasons:
- The
hawkers posed unfair competition to formal traders;
- The
hawkers caused obstructions on the sidewalks and public places;
- They
created poor impressions about the city upon visitors and tourists;
and
- The
hawkers were a menace to public health as they caused littering on
the streets.
Later,
to transform the ever-growing illegitimate small-scale retailing on the streets
of Umtata, the government issued the following regulations:
- Hawkers
had to buy a licence authorizing them to conduct their business;
- Hawkers
should be on constant move, while selling their merchandise; and
- Hawkers
were to be restricted to certain geographical areas of the town.
Despite
these restrictions, our study found out that the parallel trading business continued
to grow and was growing not only in Umtata but also in other urban centres of
Transkei. The basic reasons for the spread and development of the informal parallel
trading, which were not recognized by colonial and early post-colonial governments,
were to be found in the state of the third world capitalist political economies.
The formal capitalist economies implanted in third world countries of Africa,
Asia, and Latin America were unable to provide gainful employment to those looking
for it, especially in urban areas. In addition, the capitalist economy incorporated
all sectors of human survival. For example, all members of capitalist societies,
employed and unemployed alike, needed money to buy goods and services necessary
for life. For small traders and sellers, these small-scale activities were self-implemented
strategies for survival in the urban environments.
Notably,
the informal sources of income-generating activities, in the colonial or apartheid
era, were unnecessary because the rural-urban migration was restrained through
selective migratory policies such as influx control and pass laws. Besides,
the capitalist political economy had not yet incorporated subsistence economies.
Thus, a rural dweller could survive without money. In addition, many black people,
at this time, maintained that the urban areas were not their homes; they lived
in towns or cities for the periods they were on paid labour contracts, after
which, the contracted employees returned to their villages to be re-incorporated
into their subsistence economies. The urban areas were perceived by Africans
as residential areas (villages) of the white people. But this perception and
trends changed with political independence. The urban areas became centres of
wage-based employment, better standards of living, improved social services
and market opportunities. For these reasons, the rural and urban Africans wanted
to live in the big urban settlements.
Urbanization
in the ethnic homelands
In
the early periods of African colonization, for instance, the early explorers
and colonial administrators directed rural labour migrants towards areas with
precious minerals and raw materials. As Toure (1992) observed, this led to the
foreign capital investments and the exploitation of minerals in the Southern
African countries of Botswana, Namibia, South Africa, Zambia and Zimbabwe. The
capital investments in the mines sowed the seed of international and national
labour migration and urbanization processes into Southern Africa.
As
from the 19th century, the region, and especially South Africa, began to attract
international and internal migrants to the mines. The urban as well as rural
areas were therefore transformed through the mine economy. The mine economy
in turn led to the concentration of industrial and political economic power
in the major urban areas in South Africa. These urban towns became hubs of national
economies and centres of administrative, economic and political authority.
Despite
the apartheid policies, the urban areas pulled and attracted able-bodied black
people from rural villages who came for gainful employment in these mineral-rich
areas and administrative centres. The urban enclaves therefore contributed to
the underdevelopment of the rural areas or black homelands and the development
of the urban areas.
The
apartheid and the mines political economies became the ideal types of capitalist
investment and capital accumulation in South Africa. They became the sources
of internal uneven capitalist development and underdevelopment. To ensure a
continuous flow of cheap black labour, the white political class enacted the
Native Act of 1913, the Native Land and Trust Act in 1926 and the 1936 Bantu
Trust Land Act. These laws allocated small portions of the South African land,
about 1,221,042 Sq. Km, to black Africans while the white minority population
reserved for itself a large proportion of arable land and the mineral-rich areas
of the country. Furthermore, in 1959, the apartheid Nationalist Government "perfected"
discriminatory laws by enacting the Bantu Self-Government Act.
This
Act gave the white minority government legal bases to create internal African,
Coloured and Indian "colonies". The government granted self-governing and independent
status to ten black ethnic reserves, called "homelands" or "Bantustans". Table
1.0 below shows the ten States, population size and density and the years of
independence or self-rule. The four ethnic homelands of Transkei, Bophuthatswana,
Venda and Ciskei were granted independent status while the six black reserves
of Gazankulu, Kangwane, KwaNdebele, KwaZulu, Lebowa, and Qwaqwa were granted
self-governing status.
For
the purposes of this paper, these homelands were first pools of black labour
and suppliers of cheap migratory labour to the mines and industrialized enclaves
of white South Africa. The able-bodied labour force, mainly the males, immigrated
from the homelands to the modernized areas of South Africa. At the height of
apartheid the "immigrants" from the black homelands were considered as foreign
labour in the white areas and excluded from certain skilled jobs. Secondly,
the homelands became easily accessible markets for goods and services from South
Africa. Thus, the ideology of separate development contributed to the accumulation
of wealth in the white enclaves of South Africa. In addition, the ideology underdeveloped
the Bantustans of South Africa.
Table
1. Homeland ethnicity, population density and year of self-rule
Homelands
|
Ethnicity
|
Population
|
Pop.
Density
(Sq.Km)
|
Year
|
Bop.
Ciskei
Transkei
Venda
G.
Nkulu
K.
Ngwane
K.
Ndebele
K.
Zulu
Lebowa
Qwaqwa
|
Tswana
Xhowa
Xhosa
Venda
Shangaan
Swazi
S.
Ndebele
Zulu
N.
Sdebele
Sotho
|
3.10
0.84
3.10
0.53
0.69
0.50
0.30
4.52
2.60
0.35
|
37
73
73
67
76
77
303
109
81
329
|
1977
1981
1976
1979
1973
1984
1981
1977
1972
1974
|
Source: Population
of Homelands: Information 1992. Population Density of Homelands: Wilson
1989 Population of Self-Governing Homelands: 1991. South African Population
Census.
Social
characteristics
The
nature of these apartheid-created homelands meant that their urban centres lacked
the heterogeneous character of modern capitalist centres. The urban populations
in all the homelands were small and homogeneous, belonging mainly to one ethnic
group or tribe. Our study confirmed the homogeneity of the urban populations
in Transkei: out of the sample of 517 respondents, 84% were Xhosa, 1.93% were
Zulu, 6.77% were Sotho and about 7% belonged to other tribes. Xhosa was the
national and official language in Transkei, just as siZulu was in Zululand.
Secondly,
our sample showed that the parallel trading business was dominated by women.
Out of the sample of 517, 84% (434) were women and only about 18% (93) were
men. The mean age of the interviewees was 40 and the majority fell within the
31-50 age categories.
To
the question, "Have you been to school"?, 446 respondents answered in the positive
and only 62 said that they had never been to school. But the majority of those
who had been to school stated that they reached only Standard Five. We observed
further that the majority of our respondents were rural-urban migrants. They
told us that they were born in the rural areas. The mean number of years spent
in urban areas was approximately 17 years.
Thirdly,
we examined the marital status of our respondents. Table 2 shows that out of
189 respondents who were not married, 62.54% (156) were single women and 17.46
% (33) were single men. The mean number of children was 4.7. This Table further
demonstrates the dominance of women in all marital categories.In examining the
number of children our interviewees had, we found that about 32% (166) of the
517 people had 4-5 children. The mean number of children for the sample was
4.7. The sample further showed that, out of the 166 respondents with 4-5 children
about 89% (147) were females while only 12% (19) were males.
Table
2. Distribution of respondents by marital status
Gender
|
Single
|
Married
|
Widowed
|
Divorced
|
Separated
|
Female
Male
Total(N)
|
(156)
82.5
(33)
17.5
189
|
(157)
78.5
(43)
21.5
200
|
(69)
97.2
(2)
2.8
71
|
(17)
94.4
(1)
5.6
18
|
(29)
93.6
(2)
6.5
31
|
In
analyzing the female parameters we also discovered that 156 or (36.03%) of
the 433 females were heads of households and only 157 (or 36.26%) were married
women.
But if we include the categories widowed (69) divorced (17) and separated (29),
the total numbers of female-headed households was 271 or 62.59 percent, thus
supporting the general hypothesis of large numbers of female-headed households.
Lastly,
the ideology of separate capitalist development stifled investment possibilities
in the homelands, thereby promoting homeland emigration of the productive labour
force. The apartheid ideology discouraged White, Asian and non-Xhosa business
men and women from establishing businesses in the Transkei. As the homeland
scheme was drawn after the exploration of minerals and productive areas, the
homelands had little known wealth. The Transkei and other homelands depended,
to a large extent, on the central government for a large section of their budgets.
However,
the central government financed only the infrastructures, social services and
civil services. With the world economic embargo and apartheid-imposed restrictions,
the homelands were denied support from the international financial institutions.
Thus, with limited capitalist investments, the rural homeland towns could not
compete with the industrialized towns of white South Africa in creating jobs
and attracting rural-urban migrants.
Factors
such as female dominance, low levels of education, lack of investments, and
female-headed households pointed to the nature of urban population distribution
in Transkei. Demographic studies have revealed that females and the less educated
people are less inclined to migrate. In addition, the productive labour force
tends to migrate to areas that offer better opportunities, leaving the less
productive people in underdeveloped areas. This study, therefore, confirms these
demographic findings as the less educated people, females and children remained
in the homelands.
Table
3 compares the rural and urban population size and change in the ten Transkei
Districts in which we conducted our research. The 1980 Population Census was
taken four years after the Transkei was granted independence while the 1991
Population Census was conducted 15 years after independence. The data from the
two Censuses show that Transkei has a large rural population and a small urban
population.
The
population of Lady Frere may be explained by the fact that Lady Frere was a
black township of Queenstown. The majority of Xhosa workers in the industrial
enterprises of Queenstown lived in either Lady Frere or Ezibeleni, and commuted
to Queenstown for work and other business activities. Lady Frere, by itself,
had too little capital investment to provide urban employment. The Town Clerk
informed us that there were no industries in Lady Frere and that the Government
was the major employer. We further noted that the town had four small supermarkets,
one 10-bed hotel, three fast food shops, and two petrol stations. Lady Frere
had no financial institution.
The
population growth of Umtata was attributed to the fact that it was the Administrative
and Legislative Capital of the semi- independent State of Transkei and home
of the University of Transkei. The population growth of Butterworth in the intercensal
period (1980-1991) decreased from 56 to 40 percent. This may be explained by
the advent of a progressive military government in Bantu Holomisa. The Military
government scraped of the tax exemptions for industries in Transkei. In addition,
the military regime, through the Labour Relations Decree No.12 of 1990, liberalized
labour laws and allowed the workers to form trade unions.
Table
3. Transkei rural and urban population size and percentage change of selected
districts
|
1980
|
1991
|
|
Rural
|
Urban
|
%
Change
|
Rural
|
Urban
|
%
Change
|
B.
Worth
Engcobo
Idutwya
L.
Frere
Maluti
Mt.
Frere
Fletcher
Sterspruit
Umtata
Umzimkulu
|
48151
124408
65383
142568
112457
92780
90749
00
105699
113161
|
27343
2080
2858
19076
490
2763
1281
00
42188
4827
|
56.80
1.67
4.37
13.88
0.44
2.98
1.41
00
40.00
4.27
|
94571
217843
117384
199610
204052
136482
168712
137482
207757
252210
|
37999
3113
4262
42836
768
1921
3122
1921
93530
3519
|
40.15
1.43
3.63
21.46
0.38
1.41
1.85
1.41
45.02
1.40
|
Source: Transkei
1980 Population Census; Transkei 1991 Population Census: Preliminary Results.
In
conclusion, the 1980 urban percentage of the total population was 4.93% while
that of 1991 was 5.05%. These urban percentages of the total population were
smaller than other towns on the African Continent.
Table
4. The urban and parallel traders population of each town
Town
|
Urban
Pop.
|
Traders
Urban Pop.
|
%
of Pop.
|
Sample
|
Butterworth
Engcobo
Idutywa
Lady
Frere
Maluti/Matatiel
Mt.
Fletcher
Mt.
Frere
Sterkspruit
Umtata
Umzimkulu
Total
|
25,994(i)
1,046
1,492
1,470
N/A
415
1,348
1
420
50,081
897
81,395
|
240(ii)
85
136
50
90
48
23
47
560
92
1,440
|
0.92
8.13
9.39
3.35
0.00
11.57
9.13
11.43
1.12
10.26
|
80
40
40
40
40
40
40
40
100
40
500
|
Sources:
i. 1980 Population Census; ii. Taken on Days of Interviews 1991-1992
It
was noticed through our study that although the Transkei towns had a small urban
population they still had a number of parallel traders. Table 4.0 shows the
population of urban residents, parallel traders and the sample of traders drawn
in the towns covered by our research. This table further demonstrates the percentage
of parallel traders in relation to the population of the towns studies.
We
noticed that the percentage for the people in parallel trading was higher in
towns with a larger industrial, political and administrative base. This phenomenon
may be explained in two ways. Firstly, Umtata and Butterworth had a larger percentage
in the informal sector than other towns in Transkei because of the presence
of the public and economic bases that attracted employment seekers. The public
sector was the major employer, offering jobs to a large proportion of the labour
force. Secondly, more petty industries were located in these towns. Unlike the
smaller towns of Transkei, the public sector and economic infrastructures were
greater in Umtata and Butterworth.
We
further noticed, however, that the number of street traders fluctuated from
day to day at the time of this research. The fundamental explanation was that
parallel traders perceived the work as their own and did not feel compelled
to come to work as wage-earning employees in the formal sector. In addition,
parallel trading, as noticed in our studies, was easy to enter and depended
on non-formal skills.
Employment
options in Transkei
By
establishing the ideology of apartheid, the white political class made uneven
capitalist development and incorporation an official state policy. To facilitate
the control of black people in these territories, the white political class
governed the majority Africans through indirect rule, governing through tribal
chiefs. The white central government committed itself to provide financial assistance
to the homelands.
Table
5. Employment by sector inside Transkei, 1989
Government
Retail
and Wholesale
Manufacturing
Hotel
and Catering
Services
Banks
and Financial Institutions
Building
Construction
Total
|
87,512
22,359
14,621
10,723
7,892
8,330
3,337
154,774
|
Source:
Republic of Transkei Statistical Bulletin 1990.
The
homelands therefore lacked human entrepreneurship and capital investments to
initiate development and capital accumulation. Thus, in the homelands, the labour
force found employment mainly in the service industries, government sectors
and in the homeland parastatals. Table 5 shows the number of people employed
in the formal sector inside Transkei in 1989. The total number of people employed
in the formal sector was estimated at 154,774 or 6.00% of the Transkei de facto
population of 2.6 million people. 56.54 percent of the people in formal employment
were in the government sector with about 11.60 percent in the manufacturing,
building and construction sectors. Thus, about 32 percent found work in the
service industries.
In
this research we examined some industries that offered gainful employment in
the towns concerned. For instance, in Idutywa, a town 80km from Umtata, the
capital of Transkei, and 30Km from Butterworth, the industrial capital, the
Town Clerk told us that there were no industries that offered employment except
the service industry and the government and municipal departments. On the day
of the research we counted the following service industries:
Table
6. Number of service industries
Service
Industries
|
Number
|
1.
Hotels, Restaurants and Takeaways
2.
Clothing Shops
3.
Supermarkets
4.
Furniture Shops
5.
Banks and Insurance firms
6.
Petrol Stations
|
10
12*
8*
3
3
3
|
*
Some Supermarkets also served as Clothing Shops.
We
noted that these industries that offered paid employment to people in Transkei
were subsidiaries of companies in the former white South Africa. The black Transkei
managers were agents of the white entrepreneurs. The goods they sold came from
South Africa. We observed only a few indigenous service industries such as Transkei
National Building Society(TNBS), Transkei Development Corporation (TDC), and
Transkei Agricultural Corporation (TRACOR). Young people in Transkei, who could
not find wage employment in the homeland, either migrated to South Africa or
took to self-employment. As Table 4 above showed, 138 or 9.39 percent of the
Idutywa urban population were parallel traders.
The
employment situation in the formal sector was better in Butterworth, the industrial
town, and in Umtata, the former capital of Transkei. The Transkeian political
class chose Butterworth to be "the growth point", where industrialization was
to begin in the former homeland. The main industries that offered paid employment
in Butterworth at the time of this research are shown in Table 7. The total
urban population of Butterworth was estimated at 25,000. Thus, the number of
employees in these industries was only 15 percent of the total urban population.
Some of the people who were not employed in these industries found employment
in Government and municipal departments and Butterworth service sector industries.
At the time of the research, we counted the following service industries: 10
Hotels/Restaurants/Takeaways, 12 Supermarkets, 12 Clothing Shops, 5 Furniture
Shops, 4 Petrol Stations/Garages, and 4 financial institutions. But the government
sector, the manufacturing, textile industries and service industries could not
employ the whole labour force. Thus, 240 of the urban unemployed found work
for themselves in the informal sector.
Table
7. Industries and number of employees
Industries
|
Employees
|
1.
Pep Textile Industries
2.
Tanda Milling
3.
Tally (Pty) Ltd
4.
Sun-Textile Ltd.
5.
Ohlsson's Breweries
6.
Tannery Protea
Total
employees
|
1,600
507
500
485
400
250
3,742
|
We
found similar economic infrastructures in other small rural towns like Lady
Frere, Mt. Fletcher and Umzimkulu. Lady Frere, a rural town, 216 km from Umtata,
had an urban and rural population of 1,470 and 153,529 respectively. The Town
Clerk informed us that, apart from subsistence agriculture, the government sector
was the major employer in Lady Frere. The service industry was the second major
employer. We counted four Supermarkets, one hotel, and three takeaways, three
clothing stores, two petrol stations and one furniture shop. The town depended
on Queenstown for its financial and major shopping activities. Table 4 above
showed a small number of parallel traders. We estimated that the population
of street traders grew in relation to the level of investments and growth of
the town population and that of unemployment in Transkei.
The
military regime and parallel trading
Unlike
the civilian Matanzima regime, we found out that the military government adopted
a laisser-faire policy towards open-market traders. Although the military government
tried to regulate parallel trading business through the licensing system, the
town clerks in all the towns informed us that it was difficult both to issue
licences and to monitor a fluctuating business. It was in Umtata alone that
we noticed somme efforts at trading. The Municipal Health Officer informed us
that the Umtata Municipal Council established street committees whose main responsibilities
were to allocate "sidewalk plots" and issue licences to the applicants. Once
an applicant had been given a plot and a letter by the street committee chairperson,
he/she went to the Municipal Licensing Office for contractual details.
Nevertheless,
our findings showed that only a few sellers in Transkei had licences. Some sellers
said that they had paid a fee of R5.00 to the municipal office but no licence
had been issued to them. Other sellers told us that they had not applied for
licences. As other researchers (Nattrass, 1982; Muller, 1984; Tomaselli, 1984)
observed, the street traders were harassed under the civilian regimes. But the
Transkei Military Government leaders allowed parallel trading because they perceived
it as self-employment. The government adopted a laisser-faire trade policy to
enable petty traders to conduct their businesses without harassment.
Parallel
trading as urban self-employment
We
have reported above that the majority of our respondents spent five years in
school and that the majority of the people with low education were women. As
these people were unskilled, they were usually offered low-wage jobs in the
formal sector. This section compares the number of years and remunerations obtained
in the formal and informal parallel trading for the unskilled urban people.
First,
we examined the number of years our interviewees spent in parallel trading.
Table 8 illustrated that out of the sample of 517 people 28.41% (123) women
and 11% (15) men had been in business for more than ten years. The mean number
of years they spent in business was 10 years.
Table
8. Distribution of respondents by gender and number of years spent in parallel
trading
Gender
|
Number
of Years
|
|
<1
|
2-3
|
4-5
|
6-7
|
8-9
|
10>
|
Female
Male
Total(N)
|
(107)
86
(18)
14
125
|
(80)
75
(27)
25
107
|
(64)
83
(13)
16
77
|
(34)
76
(11)
24
45
|
(25)
100
(00)
00
25
|
(123)
89
(15)
11
135
|
Secondly,
we asked our informants why they began selling on sidewalks. Their responses
fell within the following categories: "no other job", "no source of income",
"no means to support the children" and as "self-employment". Table 9 illustrated
the various responses to our question. We have rounded up the percentages in
this table, as some of our respondents' answers were not properly framed or
were missing. These responses confirm that most of our interviewees were unemployed
people.
Table
9. Percentage distribution by gender and reasons for self-employment in parallel
trading.
Gender
|
No
Other Job
|
No
Source Income
|
Self-Employment
|
Support
Children
|
Female
Male
Total
(N)
|
(184)
81
(44)
19
228
|
(83)
85
(15)
15
98
|
(6)
46
(7)
54
13
|
(129)
94
(9)
7
138
|
Out
of 417 respondents, 228 or 55 percent of the sample reported that they were
in parallel trading because they had "no other job". 228 were in Parallel trading
because of lack of paid employment; 184 or 81 percent were women.
Thirdly,
we examined whether our respondents had any other source of income such as remittances
from their spouses and or children. Some told us that they had no spouse and
those with children said that they received no money from them. Even those who
were married informed us that they had no other source of income. Thus, street
trading was not only self-occupation but their main source of income. Parallel
trading was therefore an urban strategy for survival for the majority of these
people.
Lastly,
to explore the employability of our respondents, we asked them to tell us about
their previous paid employment. We found out that they were involved in a variety
of unskilled job categories: domestic servant/housekeeper, gardener, labourer,
shop assistant/teller at wholesale stores, night watchman and tailor. We however
observed that 34% (176) of the people had never been in gainful employment.
Furthermore, the majority of those 85% (150) who had never been employed were
females.
We
further noted that the majority of people who had been in gainful employment
worked for a short period. Out of 517 respondents, 53.77% (278) had been in
their first paid employment for less than one year and only 3.48% (18) of our
interviewees had been in formal employment for more than 20 years.
The
nature of gainful employment covered by our sample was illustrated by the amount
of money they received per month. Table 10.0 shows the various wage scales for
our interviewees. This table reveals that 387 (75%) of the people engaged in
such employment had received less than R100 per month. A few respondents indicated
that they received more than R400 a month. Furthermore, the table shows that
the females dominated the lowest wage scales while the males dominated the higher
categories. Out of 27 people who received R401 and above 17 (62.96%) were men
and only 10 were women. In contrast, 89.66% of the women and only 10.34% of
the men who had been in paid employment received less than R100 per month.
Table
10. Percentage distribution of respondents by gender and wage received per
month (in rands)
Gender
|
>R100
|
100-200
|
201-300
|
301-400
|
401>
|
Female
Male
Total(N)
|
(347)
89.66
(40)
10.34
387
|
(48)
82.76
(10)
17.24
58
|
(16)
69.57
(7)
30.43
23
|
(12)
54.55
(10)
45.45
22
|
(10)
37.04
(17)
62.96
27
|
We
also examined the nature of employment covered by our sample by asking them
to give us the reasons why they left their first paid labour. The reasons fell
in the following categories: "just left work", "business was closed", "boss
resigned and went away", "resigned because of wage dissatisfaction", became
"sick/pregnant and lost the job", and "was expelled". The number of people
who left work for these reasons was small, but these reasons point to the insignificance
of these jobs.
These
reasons and the wage received per month demonstrate that pavement sellers did
not have adequate skills for stable paid employment in the formal sector. Besides,
they received a subsistence wage for the purchase of the basic necessities of
life.
Urban
subsistence strategies
In
this study, parallel trading was envisaged as an urban subsistence economic
activity, much similar to the urban subsistence wage employment for the unskilled
workers. In general, the subsistence wage under-skilled employees received in
the formal sector did not enable them to save. In the same manner, our findings
show that the income accruing in the informal parallel trading sector was for
the day-to-day household consumption.
Table
11 illustrates that the majority (56%) of the people in our study earned less
than R20 per day.
Table 11. Percentage distribution of respondents by gender and
amount of money made per day (in rands).
Gender
|
>R10
|
11-20
|
21-30
|
31-40
|
41<
|
Female
Male
Total(N)
|
(166)
93.3
(12)
6.7
178
|
(102)
91.1
(10)
8.9
112
|
(24)
72.7
(9)
27.3
33
|
(18)
78.3
(5)
21.7
23
|
(123)
72
(48)
28
171
|
Some
added that their incomes increased "if business was good", and others said "if
people had money in their pockets". Some of our informants indicated that they
depended on the wages their customers received. Most traders said "we make
more money at the end of the month when our bosses are paid."
Our
study found out that the money parallel traders made was insufficient to meet
their household needs. Out of 517 people, 395 (76.40%) stated that the money
they earned was insufficient. For this reason, the majority of our interviewees
said they preferred paid employment to their trade. They explained that gainful
employment offered more money and better working conditions than parallel trading.
Conclusion
This
paper has examined the nature of urbanization as a factor in the development
of parallel trading in the former homeland of Transkei. We have demonstrated
with the data collected in the Transkei that the apartheid ideology of separate
ethnic and racial development stifled urbanization in the homelands. The apartheid
Influx Control Policies, the Bantu Trust Land Act and the Bantu Self-Government
Act restricted the free movement and settlement of Africans within their tribal
lands. In addition, the apartheid regime controlled not only rural-urban, and
urban migration and settlements in the South African ethnic and racial homelands,
but also the process of urbanization. Thus, the towns of Transkei were merely
large villages in which 90 percent of the urban population were Xhosa.
Secondly,
and most significantly, by controlling the process of urbanization, the apartheid
regime promoted the underdevelopment of homeland towns. We have shown that the
separate development policies facilitated capital investment in and migration
into the white areas of South Africa. By contrast, the policy cultivated the
culture of migration in the Transkei. Thus, the productive labour migrated from
the homeland, leaving the unproductive labour force.
More
importantly, the findings of this study corroborated the fact that the poverty
of the informal sector was an indication of lack of capital investments in the
towns of Transkei. Furthermore, the smallness of the informal sector and the
dominance of the female population in the sector was a consequence of migration
of productive labour force into the developed enclaves of South Africa. The
policies of apartheid have been important factors that contributed to the socio-economic
underdevelopment of the Transkei and other former homelands of South Africa.
References
- Central
Statistical Office, 1990. Republic of Transkei Statistical ulletin.
Umtata: Government Printer
- Chilivumbo,
A. 1991. "Problems Facing African Small-scale Farmers under ApartheidStructures." Paper
presented at the 34th meeting of African Studies Association, St. Louis,
USA..
- Design
Consultancy and Publishers. 1992. Transkei Directory: 1992. This is Transkei
1991/1992. Design Consultancy and Publishers.
- Government
of Transkei, 1991. "Transkei Agricultural Development Study" Policy
Document,Umtata.
- International
Labour Organization. 1972. Employment Income and Equity: A Strategy for
Increasing Productive Employment in Kenya. Geneva
- ILO-JASPA
1988. Recent Trends in Employment, Equity and Poverty in African Countries."
Paper presented at the International Conference on "The Human Dimensions
of Africa's Economic Recovery and Development", Khartoum, 1988.
- __________.
1984. "The Informal Sector in Africa", Addis Ababa.
- ___________.1986.
The Challenge of Employment and Basic Needs in Africa. Nairobi.
Oxford University Press, Nairobi.
- Letlaka,
T. 1984. "First World Norms in A Third World Environment: Problems Related
to Informal Sector Economic Activity", Transkei Development Review,
Vol.3 No.1-2.
- Mijere,
N.J. 1989. "Youth and Development of Self-Reliance in Zambia"in
Osei-Hwedie and Ndulo (eds) Studies in youth and Development London:
Commonwealth Secretariat
- Muller,
N. 1984. "The Political Economy of Employment and Unemployment in Transkei
1970-1980: The Place of the Survival Economy, Transkei Development
Review, vol.3 no.1-2.
- Nattrass,
J. 1982. The South African Economy: Its Growth and Change, Cape
Town: Oxford University Press
- Nattrass,
N.J. 1984. "The Informal Sector: Implications for Employment in Transkei", Transkei development Review,
Vol.3 no. 1-3.
- Ncube,
P and Sisulu, M. 1991. "The Informal Sector, Small Scale Industries and
Redistribution in a Free South Africa" Working Paper 1.University
of the Western Cape.
- Nduna,
J. 1990. " The Struggles for Survival of Street Traders in Umtata, Transkei", GeoJournal Vol.
22 No.3.
- Osirim,
M. 1994. "Women, Work, and Public Policy: Structural Adjustment and the
Informal Sector in Zimbabwe" in Ezekiel Kalipeni (ed.) Population Growth
and Environmental Degradation in Southern Africa, Boulder: Lynne
Rienner Publishers.
- Rogerson,
C.M. 1985. "The Under-development of the Informal Sector: Street Hawking
in Johannesburg, South Africa" in John I. Clarke (ed) Population
and development Projects in Africa, Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
- Seshamani,
V. 1990. The Informal Sector in Zambia: An Overview of Issues, Problems
and Prospects", University of Zambia: Lusaka
- Southall,
R. 1982. The Political Economy of an Independent Bantustan,
London:Heinemann
- Tomaselli,
R. 1984. "The Hawkers of Umtata: Economic Refugees or Folk Devils", Transkei Development Review,
vol.3. No.1-3.
- Weeks,
J. 1975. "Policies for Expanding Employment in the Informal Sector of
Developing Countries", International Labour Review 111, Geneva.
- Wilson,
F. and Ramphele, M. 1989. Uprooting Poverty: The South African Challenge,
Cape Town: David Philip.
- Wirth,
L. 1938. "Urbanise as a way of life", American Journal of Sociology
44, pp.1-24
- Yankson,
P.W.K. 1991. Urbanization and Employment Generation in Ghanaian Towns:
A Comparative Study of the Role of the Informal Sector in Tamale and Tema.
Dakar. Union for African Population Studies.
Copyright 1997 - Union for African Population
Studies.
|